Success 2.0: Getting What You Want

We all rely on incentives to get people to do things they might otherwise avoid. Parents reward kids for doing their homework. Companies offer bonuses to their high-performing employees. Charities send gifts to their donors. In the second episode in our “Success 2.0” series, economist Uri Gneezy shares how incentives can help us to achieve our goals, if we know how to avoid their pitfalls.

For more Hidden Brain on incentives, listen to our episode on awards.

Additional Resources

Books:

Mixed Signals: How Incentives Really Work, by Uri Gneezy, 2023.

The Why Axis: Hidden Motives and the Undiscovered Economics of Everyday Life, by Uri Gneezy and John A. List, 2013.

Research:

Exercise Improves Academic Performance, by Alexander W. Cappelen et al., NHH Dept. of Economics Discussion Paper, 2017.

The Counterintuitive Effects of Thank-You Gifts on Charitable Giving, by George E. Newman and Jeremy Shen, Journal of Economic Psychology, 2012.

Incentives to Exercise, by Gary Charness and Uri Gneezy, Econometrica, 2009.

Large Stakes and Big Mistakes, by Dan Ariely, Uri Gneezy, George Lowenstein, and Nina Mazar, The Review of Economic Studies, 2009.

The Inefficiency of Splitting the Bill, by Uri Gneezy, Ernan Haruvy, and Hadas Yafe, The Economic Journal, 2004.

A Fine is a Price, by Uri Gneezy and Aldo Rustichini, The Journal of Legal Studies, 2000.

Pay Enough or Don’t Pay at All, by Uri Gneezy and Aldo Rustichini, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2000.

The transcript below may be for an earlier version of this episode. Our transcripts are provided by various partners and may contain errors or deviate slightly from the audio.

Shankar Vedantam:

This is Hidden Brain. I'm Shankar Vedantam. A few years after the Communist Revolution brought Mao Zedong to power, China's leader ordered his people to exterminate four pests, rats, flies, mosquitoes and sparrows. The birds were eating China's grain. Chairman Mao had recently collectivized agriculture and he wanted to kill off the birds consuming his country's food. During the Great Sparrow campaign, as the effort was called, millions of birds were killed. People shot sparrows or banged on pots and pans until the birds fell to the ground in exhaustion.

But the eradication of the sparrows produced an unintended consequence. Insect population soared because one of their natural predators had been eliminated. Locusts swept across China's fields, decimating crops and contributing to a great famine. Official figures put the death toll at 15 million people, unofficial numbers were two to five times higher.

While the scale of the disaster was unimaginable, China is hardly alone when it comes to wrong-headed policies. From nations and governments to companies and families, humans regularly fail to foresee how initiatives can backfire. This week we continue our series, Success 2.0, with a look at one of the principal sources of failure in our lives, unintended consequences. How to expect the unexpected when we plan for the future, this week on Hidden Brain.

Much of life is about getting others to behave in the way we want. We come up with carrots and sticks to persuade children to do their homework, prompt partners to pick up their socks, and motivate coworkers to do their best. But often these inducements are ineffective. Sometimes they even backfire. Uri Gneezy is an economist at the University of California San Diego. He studies how we craft incentives and smart ways to do it better. Uri Gneezy, welcome to Hidden Brain.

Uri Gneezy:

Thank you. Great to be here.

Shankar Vedantam:

Uri, when you were a child growing up in Tel Aviv, in Israel, the heroes of Israeli society were the fighter pilots who served in Israel's Air Force. When you were 11 or 12 years old, you heard a story about these fighter pilots that made quite an impression on you. Tell me that story.

Uri Gneezy:

So, in Israel, being a fighter pilot was the highest social status you can have, and everyone wanted to be one, including me. So, think about Top Gun on steroids. And my hobby was to read all these World War II books and other books about fighter pilots going out and shooting down enemy airplanes and becoming heroes.

And so I remember this story that I read about the Six-Day War. There was a Mirage pilot that told the story. He was there with his three buddies. The four planes were looking for Egyptian MiGs over the Suez Canal, and suddenly he saw two of them in the horizon and he turned immediately over there. His friends didn't see where he went, and they asked him and he said that he just is chasing the MiGs to the west when he actually chased them to the east. And basically what he did was trying to get these MiGs by himself, to shoot them down by himself.

Now, if he worried about the country and safety and the chance of actually doing this, he would've called his buddies to join him because that's much better. But no, he really wanted to shoot them down by himself. So, he lied to them and he was after that, he was very proud of it. So, that shows that the incentives are really working in this case. It might be a funny way, but remember like you said, when I was 11 or 12, thinking about, "Okay, so that's the real incentive." That's what motivates him. That's what gets this guy to go and risk his life because he really wanted the social status that came up with shooting down the MiGs.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, it's interesting, the very high status awarded to pilots, you could say that that's a good thing for a country to be doing. Because of course by recognizing soldiers and pilots, the country basically incentivizes people to want to join the armed forces and to protect the country. But what you're showing here is that that incentive now can actually change people's behavior in ways that actually don't serve the best interests of the country.

Uri Gneezy:

Right. You get the best people to actually want and to go out and shoot enemy planes, risking their life. But in some cases it can really make you do stupid things because now your motivation is not completely aligned with the organization. The organization, in this case the state of Israel, wanted the MiGs to be shut down and you to be safe.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, sometime later when you were a teenager, you and your classmates knocked on doors each year to raise money for charity. And one year your teachers came up with an incentive to get kids to do a better job. Tell us how the charity program worked, what kind of activities you did each year with your friends and what the incentive was that teachers came up with that one year.

Uri Gneezy:

So, when I grew up in Israel we used to go out a few times a year to collect money for charities like the Cancer Association or Kids in Danger. And together with another 15, 16 year old kid, you went around, knocked on doors, and tried to raise money. Now, you didn't have to persuade the donors because they knew exactly what it is. And the more doors you knocked on, the more success you had.

And I remember as a kid that I was very happy when I got to the age when I could participate in this. And my friend and I, we went out and tried to knock on as many doors. We got receipts for 500 shekels, which was about $170, $180 at the time. But then there were also some kids who didn't do anything, they just didn't go. And the teacher came up with the brilliant incentive scheme. She said, "If you raise at least 100 shekels, then you won't have to do homework over the weekend.

And it worked. So, it was a brilliant incentive in the sense that now everyone went out and collected at least 100 shekels. But actually many of us, including me, stopped now at a hundred shekels. And as a result, what happened is more kids actually went out, but the overall collection was much smaller than before.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, in some ways the incentive was trying to change the behavior of the weakest performers. And in fact, it successfully did so, but at the cost of undermining the performance of the strongest performers.

Uri Gneezy:

Exactly. And overall performance as well.

Shankar Vedantam:

One last example I want to touch on. Years later after you became a parent yourself, you once took your son to Disney World and you spotted a sign setting out the ticket prices for admission to the park. What did the sign say, Uri?

Uri Gneezy:

So, the sign said if you are under three years old, it's free. Over three years old, it's $117. Now, my son just turned three a couple of months earlier and I loved that period because he started communicating. You can talk with them, it's a lot of fun. But they also start lying when they start talking. That's also very, very human, right? And of course as parents, we told him that he shouldn't lie, only bad kids lie.

So, we got to the counter and then I saw that if the kid is under three, it's free. And the cashier asked me, "How old is your kid?" I looked at him and I said, "Well, he is almost three." Now, it wasn't a lie completely because he was almost three, but from the wrong direction. But I lied and got to pay whatever. And then we started walking and about half an hour later my son pulled my shirt and said, "Daddy, daddy, you told me that only bad people lie. And now you just lied." And of course I turned pale and my reaction was something of the sort of do as I say and not as I do.

A few minutes later we got to another attraction and this one my son, Ron, really wanted to do it, but it turns out that he needed to be at least four in order to be able to go on it. And Ron, without hesitation said, "Yeah, I'm four." And turns out that what he actually learned was not to do as I say, but to do as I do.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, you saved $117 on Ron's ticket, but the price was that you sent your three-year-old kid the message that lying is okay.

Uri Gneezy:

Exactly.

Shankar Vedantam:

And I guess the question to ask then is, was that the right price to pay for the message that you were sending your kid?

Uri Gneezy:

I think that that's exactly the question. So, when you do something like that, you need to think, "Is it worth $117 in order to send this message?" In some cases you might say, "Yes." But in retrospect, no it wasn't. I wouldn't have done it again.

Shankar Vedantam:

Classical economics presents us with a very simple understanding of incentives. Incentives can get people to do things they might not otherwise do. Once an incentive is introduced, people's motivation will increase as you increase the size of the reward. But the way incentives play out in real life is considerably more complicated. When we come back, we peel back the layers of the incentives' onion to understand why it's so hard to get other people to do what we want. You're listening to Hidden Brain. I'm Shankar Vedantam.

This is Hidden Brain, I'm Shankar Vedantam. Uri Gneezy works at the University of California San Diego. When he was being trained as an economist, he was taught that incentives were simple and straightforward. Pay someone to do something, they'll do it. The more you pay them, the harder they'll work. But over many years of experience and research, Uri has come to see that reality is a lot more complicated. Uri, I'm wondering if we could start with the basics. What is an incentive and what kind of signal is it designed to send?

Uri Gneezy:

So, incentive is something that will motivate you to do an activity or produce something or whatever, that you wouldn't do without it. And one of the problems with setting incentives is that many people don't understand that these incentives are not just giving you some kind of material payoff, they also send you a signal about what's important for me. And this signal is something that can really impact behavior.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, poorly crafted incentives can backfire and that they can actually discourage people from doing things you want them to do. But it's sometimes hard to tell when an incentive is poorly crafted. For example, we all know that it's nice to say thank you when someone does something nice for us. But the social scientist, George Newman and Jeremy Shen once looked at the effect of thank you gifts on charitable contributions. Tell me what they found, Uri.

Uri Gneezy:

So, they found that if you give people a gift after, a thank you gift, say, a coffee mug, it can actually backfire and get people to donate less. And I think that the reason is that it basically changes the meaning of what you are doing. Turning the situation into some kind of exchange. Now, I'm not doing it because I'm a nice guy, I'm doing it because I want this bag or pen or whatever the gift is. And then I say, "Well, I'm not going to spend $100 on this pen or this bag. It's not worth it." It completely changes the way I perceive the interaction. And because of that, I want to do the activity even less than before.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, sending unclear or contradictory signals can change the way people think about a particular situation. And in some ways it can lead them to engage in behavior that is the opposite of what you're trying to encourage. There's a somewhat related story involving the Welsh government. Officials wanted to crack down on parents who pull kids out of school for family vacations. Presumably the policymakers wanted to keep kids in class so they could learn more, right?

Uri Gneezy:

Right. So, anyone who had kids and wanted to go on vacation knows that that's the worst time to go. So, when you have breaks from school, that's where everything is more crowded, more expensive, less pleasant. And some parents decided, "You know what? We'll take our kids off school say a week before or a week after the spring break. That way we'll save money and we'll have a nicer vacation because it's going to be less crowded."

The government didn't want to do it. And it introduced a small fine. I believe it was £60 if you did that. Now, the situation that the parents faced was very different. Before that it was, look, the teachers are not going to like it. The principal is not going to like it. Good parents won't do that. Now the story is, "Oh, if we'll do that, it's £60."

You put a price on this activity and now instead of being immoral, now it's like, "Well, for £60 I can save much more money by going a week earlier." And turns out that many parents decided to do it and some travel agencies even offered to pay this fine for people.

Shankar Vedantam:

Oh, my gosh.

Uri Gneezy:

Because it was so much better to do it this way, right? Everyone is happier apart from the schools that were less happy.

Shankar Vedantam:

One of the things that's tricky about incentives is that in any situation there is often more than one motivator at play. So, an incentive can amplify one source of motivation, but sometimes at the expense of something else. And that something else might actually be more important. Uri once saw this play out in British professional soccer where a team was awarding bonuses to individual players for every goal they scored.

Uri Gneezy:

As a soccer player there are different ways to motivate you, to incentivize you. One of them is just to pay your salary. Another one pays you per victory. Another one is per scoring a goal or for assist if you send the ball to someone else. So, there was a situation in which if you scored the goal, you got £75,000. If you sent an assist that ended up in a goal, you got £20,000.

Now, imagine that you're facing two options. One option is to try and run yourself and score yourself. Say that you have 50% chance of succeeding, then you have 50% chance of getting £75,000. Or you can send it to your friend and say that your friend has 75% chance of scoring it. So, now you'll get lower than if you try yourself.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, in other words, passing the ball will get you less money than trying to score yourself, even though the odds of you scoring are actually lower than if you pass the ball.

Uri Gneezy:

Exactly. Exactly. So, now the team clearly cares about scoring the goal. They don't care who's going to do it, they want to win. That's what the coach and management try to incentivize. And I'm sure that the coach told everyone, all the players, "Look, we are a team, we want you to be a team player..." and blah, blah, all the good stuff.

But the signal that the incentive sent was very different than the signal that the coach told them before. Now, it's a complicated situation because in some cases if you want to attract the best players in the world, if you want to attract the Messi of the world, you really need to pay them a lot per success. But at least don't send a message telling them that you care about team game and incentivize individual success. That's not going to work.

Shankar Vedantam:

This is a little bit like the story of the Israeli pilot, right? Which is - the Israeli pilot cared more about his own glory than about what was actually best for the country.

Uri Gneezy:

Exactly. And still, I'm not saying that that's necessarily a bad incentive, because these incentives really motivate the fighter pilot and the soccer player to do their best. But in some cases it could create a problem.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, it's also the case that in group settings, different people often have competing incentives. Uri, I want to play you a clip from the TV show Friends. This scene is unfolding at a restaurant.

Waiter:

And for gentlemen?

Joey:

Yeah, I'll have the Thai chicken pizza.

Waiter:

Miss?

Rachel:

Oh, okay. I will have the side salad.

Waiter:

And for you?

Phoebe:

I'm going to have a cup of the cucumber soup.

Chandler:

I will have the Cajun catfish.

Shankar Vedantam:

Everyone enjoys their meal. Then the bill arrives.

Ross:

Okay, everyone owes 28 bucks.

Phoebe:

Everyone? No Uh-huh, no way. Sorry. Not going to happen. Rachel just had that...

Shankar Vedantam:

So, Uri, you've talked about a problem known as the unscrupulous diner's dilemma. What is this dilemma?

Uri Gneezy:

So, I love this clip from Friends. Basically what happens is that if you know that you're going to split the bill, then what the economists called, your marginal cost goes down. So, imagine that there are five people in the restaurant and we are going to split the bill. So, if I spend another $10 on my main dish, I will actually pay only $2 out of that because the other people are going to pay the rest. So, then my calculation becomes very different. Before that I would say, "Well, the lobster costs $50, I don't want to spend that much." Now I say, "Well the lobster will actually cost me only $10. I should go for it, right? That's my chance."

And that's indeed what we found in our experiment. We brought students to an actual restaurant and we saw what happened when we told them that we're going to split the bill versus when we told them that each one will pay for themself. So, they ordered more, they ordered the drinks, suddenly they were real festive. And by the way, it was true for men and women. The entire bill was so much higher when they split the bill, that it was funny to see. In many cases restaurants will say, "If you're a group bigger than X, we want you to actually split the bill." And that could be one of the motivations. They know that people order more when they split the bill.

Shankar Vedantam:

Now, we've looked at how incentives are designed to send signals, but of course the signals we're sending are not being heard by computers or robots. They're being heard by human beings. And human beings don't just respond to the signal. They ask, "What is this signal really about? What is it telling me?" During the COVID pandemic, Uri, some states like Ohio decided to encourage their citizens to get vaccinated using a rather unusual incentive. Tell me what they did.

Uri Gneezy:

So, they offered a lottery that will give you say a million dollars. Some of them were even higher than that. So, they're going to go to all the people that got vaccinated this week and one of them is going to get a million dollars in the lottery. Which is great, it's nice. What can go wrong?

So, here's a thought experiment. Imagine that someone invites you to join a test for a new drug. They tell you that's a headache pill that you can take and your headache will go away and there are no side effects that we know and we'll pay you $50 for participating. That's basically what the FDA does in many cases and I think that it makes sense to do. And I would be willing to take part in such a study.

Now, imagine that it's the same, but they tell you, "We'll pay you $50,000 for participating." Now, I'll be worried, right? If there are no side effects, why are they offering me so much money to take this one pill? And I think that this signal, that if you're paying me a million dollars to get vaccinated, it must be really bad for me to get vaccinated, right? Because otherwise why do you have to pay me to do it?

Shankar Vedantam:

Yeah.

Uri Gneezy:

Remember that we talked about completing the story. This completes the story in a different way than you intended. You wanted to tell him, "Look, I care about you so much that I'm willing to pay you because it's so important and the bad things that can happen are so bad that I want to encourage you." That was your story. But the story that the people may hear is that, "this is actually bad for you. It's so bad that we are willing to pay you a million dollars to do it."

Shankar Vedantam:

Another dimension of incentives that makes them tricky has to do with the fact that the people we're trying to influence perceive not just a carrot but also a stick. So, when people don't achieve an objective, they start to ask, "What's going to happen if I fail?" Uri, tell me what happened at Wells Fargo Bank in the early 2000s when they introduced an incentive to increase performance.

Uri Gneezy:

So the CEO had a great idea. "I want every customer that we have to have at least eight products from the bank. So, if the customer has, say, a checking account, I want her to also have a credit card and savings account and whatever." And they gave very strong incentives for the people working in the bank to actually do that. And actually, if you did not meet the goals that they gave, it's not only that you didn't get the incentives, you were also very likely to be fired because your colleagues were able to do it.

Now, turns out that it's very hard to do it and the way the colleagues were able to do it is by making up accounts. So, think about the image of a worker coming to the bank in the morning, drinks his or her coffee, sit down at the computer and start making up fake accounts.

Newscaster:

According to authorities inside Wells Fargo, employees called it gaming. Forging customer signatures, creating pins to activate unauthorized debit cards and moving money to unauthorized accounts.

Yeah, I had 15 accounts at once. It was just very frustrating. And these are accounts I never opened.

Uri Gneezy:

And it wasn't one or two people. We're talking about over 3 million accounts and they fired at the end over 5,000 people for doing this. So, basically the CEO wanted to have more products per account, got exactly what he wanted. The stock of Wells Fargo went up. Everything was fine apart from the fact that it was all a balloon that was clearly going to explode at one point because it was all fake.

Shankar Vedantam:

I'm wondering if part of the problem here, Uri, is that the leaders were trying to incentivize an explicit behavior, which is to aggressively sell the company's products, but they ignored how this incentive might affect other behaviors including the implicit norm. To be honest, they probably weren't thinking at that at the point they set up the incentive program, "Well, what happens when people don't meet this target? What are they going to do?"

Uri Gneezy:

So, giving people incentives to create extra accounts is not bad in itself. It will work, people will try harder. But at the same time, they had to put some safety measures that will make sure that people don't lie. So, when you design incentives like this, think about: how can people try and game the incentive? Because that's what we do. We game the incentives all the time. We are very good at it. We are very creative with it.

So, for example, if there was enough auditing done and once you catch someone making up an account, you immediately fired that person, that would've worked. But instead what happened is that even the whistleblower that came to management and said, "This is happening," they were actually fired. So, the incentive in itself wasn't bad. It just lacked the safety measure that was needed.

Shankar Vedantam:

You cite a revealing incident from colonial era Vietnam. French authorities were confronting a problem and they came up with a solution. It involved incentivizing ordinary people to go out and kill rats. But that incentive ended up producing a problem of its own. Tell me what happened, Uri.

Uri Gneezy:

So, the French wanted to introduce toilets to Hanoi, which is very French of them to do. And when the toilets were introduced, you also need sewage. And with sewage come the rats. So, there was a big problem with rats and the authorities were very smart. He said, "Let's pay say 10 cents per rat tail that you bring." So, there was a poor guy in the city hall that was counting rat's tails, and for each one of them he gave 10 cents.

That sounds again like a very good incentive that, what can go wrong? That's you give the people you let the people go after the rats, everything's going to be well. Well, it turns out, for example, that people just cut the tail of the rat and let the rat go free, because the rat can have more babies that way. Some of them started the rat farms, so they started raising their own rats in order to harvest their tails. Some of them brought rats from neighboring cities in order to cut their tails. So, again, people are really good at gaming the incentives and you need to find a way and incentives that actually is robust to such manipulation.

Shankar Vedantam:

It's interesting because I think this draws attention to the fact that when you're leading a company or a city or a country, it's very easy to focus on something that is not going well and come up with a simple plan to fix that thing. But the problematic thing usually doesn't exist in a vacuum, it's connected to other things or it can influence things one layer beneath the surface. And in some ways I think what all these examples are pointing to is the complexity of human behavior and perhaps how we need to exercise a certain amount of humility when it comes to trying to engineer that behavior.

Uri Gneezy:

So, when I work with companies, very often I hear some version of, "We tried incentives and they didn't work." And when I hear this, I think about someone who went to a bad Japanese restaurant and his or her conclusion is, Japanese food is bad. No, that's not the right conclusion. You went to a bad restaurant. And the same is true about incentives. It's not that incentives don't work, it's just that you didn't understand the complexity of incentives.

Shankar Vedantam:

Incentives are powerful tools. They can make people act in ways they would not if left to their own devices. But misunderstood or misapplied, incentives can backfire and boomerang. When we come back, how to craft incentives that get yourself and others moving in the direction of success. You're listening to Hidden Brain. I'm Shankar Vedantam.

This is Hidden Brain. I'm Shankar Vedantam. Economist Uri Gneezy is the author of Mixed Signals, How Incentives Really Work. He studies the science of how we use carrots and sticks to get others to behave the way we want. Uri, when someone crafts an incentive, the people being incentivized use the signal of the incentive to draw conclusions about the sender. So poorly designed or poorly presented incentives can backfire by making the creator of the incentive look callous or greedy. You recently observed this in an initiative launched by a movie theater chain. Can you tell m e what happened?

Uri Gneezy:

So, recently AMC decided to have different prices for different seats. They understood that people don't like to sit upfront or on the sides and their solution was - let's raise the price for the middle seats, for the premium seat. And that's what airlines are doing, that's what hotels are doing. But the way they did it really created a pushback.

Many people were upset. "The prices are already so high and now you're charging us more for the premium seats. That's really a nasty behavior." That's the story that people heard. But instead of that, AMC could have said, "Look, we are sorry. Prices are so high, the inflation, whatever, we need to raise our prices. We are sorry. But here's the good news. We are going to give you discount if you're willing to sit in the first row or on the sides."

So, exactly the same incentives, but frame them. Tell the story, fill up the story in a way that instead of, "I'm greedy and want to take even more money from you," is the story that you're telling is, "Look, we are trying to help you and we are offering this discount on less desirable seats."

Shankar Vedantam:

So, in other words, let's say for example the ticket prices were $10 and you're charging $15 for the premium seats. What you're saying is raise the ticket prices to $15 for everyone and then basically make the less attractive seats discounted to $10. It comes to the same thing, but the story becomes completely different.

Uri Gneezy:

Exactly, exactly. Instead of, "I'm taking advantage of you whenever I can," it's, "I'm trying to help you whenever I can. I had to raise prices because everything costs more. We have to pay more for our workforce, we have to pay more for rent so we had to do this. But we really care about the people that have a hard time paying and we really want them to actually keep coming."

Shankar Vedantam:

So, this points of course to the importance of paying attention, not just to the incentive, but the story that the incentive is communicating. Some companies have found a way to use incentives to tell a consistent story about their values. And you say that one such company is the sandwich chain Pret a Manger. How do they design incentives, Uri?

Uri Gneezy:

So, they wanted to give you some kind of bonus like employee of the week or something like that and give you a bonus. Now, in every case that you're doing something like this, you're actually doing something else as well. It's not just the people that you invite to the party, it's also the people that you don't invite that you should care about. So, the people that, in this case, did not get the bonus. In this case, the bonus was $50. And the way they thought to reduce the problem was that if you were the employee of the week or of the month, you got $50 but you were asked to spend it on someone else, on one of your friends.

Shankar Vedantam:

So, the incentive on the surface is designed to reward people for reaching a milestone. But really the way the company is using it, the incentive is designed to enhance team building.

Uri Gneezy:

Yes, if it's a subjective measure, for example, how well you did on something that we can't measure in dollars, then I'm going to be upset if you'll get the reward because I'm clearly better than you. This way it reduced by a lot the tension between the employees about who's going to win this. So, winning it was, you still got the status and it was nice, you felt good about yourself, but the money you gave to other people. So, other people, the workers, became more friendly with each other and there was less tension over there.

Shankar Vedantam:

One problem with incentives is that people will change their behavior for as long as they're being incentivized to do so, but will then revert to their previous behavior once the incentive is withdrawn. Your own research however, has shown that incentives can create long-lasting change if they're used in a particular way. Tell us about your study about building exercise habits, Uri.

Uri Gneezy:

So, creating habits is maybe the holy grail of incentives. How can we change your habits? How can we get you to exercise more, stop smoking or diet better? Whatever is the activity that you want to do. It turns out to be very difficult. Because it's an ongoing behavior which is very hard to change. And many of us, those of us that struggle with this, including me, remember periods of their life in which they exercise.

So, there were periods in my life in which I exercised. I was very happy about going to the gym or surfing or biking, whatever it is. And then I have periods in my life in which I can't get myself off the couch. The only physical activity is watching Netflix. What's the difference between these two? And what we thought about, and there is some literature suggesting this, that once you get into the activities, so say for a month after that, it's much easier.

So, the first time you go to the gym, it smells bad. You don't know where to park, you don't know what to do. It's kind of embarrassing. After a month, suddenly you don't bother the smell that much and you know exactly what you're going to do. And say you put it in your schedule that Monday and Thursday at 9:00 AM I'm going to do yoga classes, whatever it is that you're doing. Suddenly it becomes much easier for you.

And the idea was that if you can build this, if you can invest in this month, even if you're going to suffer and you think that the suffering is bigger than the benefit, just invest in this month and then after that it might become really easier. So, we did it with incentives. It was Gary Charnessa and I. So, we pay students a hundred dollars to go to the gym eight times for a month. And then after that we stopped paying them. And we saw that the people that got paid to go to the gym were much more likely to go to the gym than the control group.

So, we did create some kind of habit. Turns out that this habit dies quite fast. So, if winter break they come back, the habit is dead. So, how to maintain this habit is still a question, but it is interesting that if I can get you over this hurdle of actually going to the gym a few times, it's going to be easier. Now, you can also think about it for yourself. You can incentivize yourself. The first time you go, like we said, you're going to suffer but you should commit. "I'm going to force myself to go for a month and only then I'm going to evaluate whether I want to continue or not." And you might be surprised by the outcome.

Shankar Vedantam:

A related idea is that incentives can also be used to help people get past what you call switching costs. What are these, Uri?

Uri Gneezy:

So, switching costs is something that we do all the time. So we have this, imagine going to the supermarket. You know which kind of shampoo you're going to buy or toilet paper. Maybe at the beginning you searched a bit, but then you chose one brand of toilet paper and that's what you're taking. Switching to another one will require standing over there thinking about it, comparing prices. Is it soft enough or not? You're not going to do it. You're going to stay with the toilet paper that you know.

Now imagine that you go, you reach to your regular toilet paper and you see that the competitor has a discount, half price say. Now you're saying, "Wow, that's a big discount. Let me try the other one. I'll try it." You'll take it, try it and if you like it you might switch to it and when you go back you'll actually search for it because you like it, even if there won't be a discount on it.

So, there is a switching cost, which is, it could be a mental switching cost like that, you just don't want to think about it. There could be some other switching cost, like imagine now smoking, for example. Imagine that I can actually pay you to stop smoking for a month. Maybe after a month it's going to be less attractive for you to go back. And that's the idea, right? So, switching from one activity to another is costly. If I'll give you a discount, if I'll give you incentives, I might get you to change your behavior in a way that you wouldn't do after that. And if I'm lucky, you'll stick with the new behavior later on.

Shankar Vedantam:

In many parts of our lives we don't see the consequences of our actions until much later. So, if you start smoking for example, it can take years or even decades before you pay the price in terms of health effects. The same thing goes for schooling, but in the opposite direction. It often takes years before you can see the benefits of studying hard and doing well at school. You and others have done a lot of thinking about this problem and how incentives might be used to try and improve the performance of students in school. Tell me about this work, Uri.

Uri Gneezy:

So, as a university professor, my life is quite boring. I don't get that many people mad at me, unless I go and talk about incentives with educators. They want to kill me, they want to choke me very fast. And I think that they're right in many cases because you want the students to have intrinsic motivation to be successful. You don't want to pay the money in order to read books. And we know that they can pay you money to read the book, I can't pay you to start enjoying the books.

So, it's much harder and I'll sympathize with the teachers and the educators that say this. However, there are things that you can actually use in education that will be useful. So, my example is, I write a lot for my living and yet I write one finger at a time. I don't know how to type. If someone would've paid me enough money or convinced me to invest a week in learning touch typing, that would have been amazing for me.

So, once you learn a skill, you're not going to go back. And in education you can think about some landmarks like them that are important. Imagine your annoying teenager and the SAT. You understand how important it is, you really want your kid to be successful, but they have other things in mind. If you can find incentives to make sure that they actually prepare well for the SAT, that could still work. The bigger problem, in which I agree with the teachers and the educator, is that you can use it in order to get kids, students to enjoy what they're doing. That we don't know how to do. And that's much harder.

Shankar Vedantam:

At the same time it seems like, I think the picture you're painting here, is that incentives are perhaps potentially useful in these narrow circumstances where the student basically is unable to really comprehend how applying himself or herself in school can pay off 20 or 30 years down the road. But a carefully targeted incentive can prompt the student to do better on a standardized test, for example. Three week sprint, for example. And that might in fact have long-term consequences that are beneficial.

Uri Gneezy:

That's true, but I wouldn't be that pessimistic about the first part, because if you use the right incentives, you can make, you actually studying more enjoyable. We have a recent paper in which we looked at the effect of physical activity on success, academic success. So, imagine that all you care about is the math success, success in math for the kids. And currently they get 10 hours of math and two hours of physical education every week.

Now you have to cut two hours. Which one should you cut? Should you cut down the two PE classes like most schools do or maybe two hours of the math? Even if all you care about is the math performance. It could be, and that's what we find. We find that students that are engaged in physical activity are actually doing much better academically.

So, it might be better to take the two hours for math, let them run around and go back. And this could be used also as incentives, right? So, if I tell you, "Look, finish up the work and you can go out and play some basketball," that could be used as incentives. So, the kids will enjoy coming to school more and everything around it will become nicer. So, I wouldn't be as pessimistic as, "We can't do anything," but we need to be very careful.

Shankar Vedantam:

Uri, when it comes to designing incentives, it's really important to pay attention to the size of the incentives that you're designing. You've run studies looking at the risks of running incentives that are too small. Tell me about that work.

Uri Gneezy:

So, we had the same setup with the kids collecting money in these special donation days. An, what we wanted to do is compare kids that are just motivated by, that's the right thing to do, you should go out and get it, with kids that get a small kickback. So, we offered them 1% of what they collected. So, if you collected $200, you got $2 as a reward, which is very little.

And what we found was that when we offered this reward, these incentives, kids were much more likely to stay home and not go out to collect money. Because now they said, "well it's only $2, it's not worth it, right? I'm not going to put all this effort." So, Aldo Rustichini and I ran an experiment like that. And the title I think is really revealing. We called it Pay Enough or Don't Pay At All.

So, the point is that if you would've offered these kids a hundred dollars, they would've collected all the money they can. But when you offer too little you change the story. Before that the story was, "I'm doing it because that's the right thing to do." Now, when you offer incentives, "I'm doing it because I'm getting paid. Well if I'm getting paid, pay me enough, otherwise don't pay me."

Shankar Vedantam:

You've also done some research that suggests that making an incentive too large can cause people to choke, especially on tasks involving cognitive capacity such as attention and memory. Can you tell us about the study you conducted looking at the effect of very large incentives on performance?

Uri Gneezy:

So, think about public speaking or imagine that I ask you to do, say, free shot in basketball. But I don't know how good you are, maybe you'll do two out of 10. Now, imagine that I'll pay you a million dollars if you'll be successful.

Shankar Vedantam:

Oh, boy.

Uri Gneezy:

Right. Exactly. So, things that you would've done automatically before that, now you started thinking about it. And turns out that in many cases thinking about it is much less good than just doing it automatically. So just don't tell me that you'll give me a million dollars, I have a 20% chance of doing it. If you'll offer me a million dollars, I'd probably be so far off because I'll be too excited.

And that's basically what we found. We found that in cases in which thinking is not what you need to do, you really need to follow your instinct and do the automatic things, people were less successful when we did this. They basically choked under pressure.

Shankar Vedantam:

You said that incentives can also be a powerful truth seeking device. They can reveal preferences that would otherwise remain hidden. I understand that some companies offer to pay employees to quit their jobs. Why would they do this, Uri?

Uri Gneezy:

I love this. So, I teach negotiation and I tell my students that the only time that they should lie is when they're interviewed for a job. They need to show excitement. If you're not excited about the job, why would I hire you? But because of that, if I'm the employer, I want to keep only the people that really want to be there because they're much more productive. But if I'll ask you, "Are you excited to work for me?" You'll say, "Yes, of course." How can I actually use incentives to find out who really cares about me?

Instead of asking you, "Are you excited to work for me?" I'll tell you, "Look, Shankar, here's $10,000 if you want to leave, you're welcome to leave. Thank you for working with us. We are happy and good luck." Now, if you are happy to work for me, you'll say, "No, no, no. Thank you. I don't want the $10,000. I'm happy over here." And if you are on the margin and you're not sure, you'll just take the $10,000 we'll depart as friends, which is also important because otherwise you can badmouth me, you can sabotage. I don't want to fire you.

So, I can really select on the people that want to be with me in the company. And by the way, it could have other effects. So, now because I gave up $10,000, I really have to justify this. If I'll go to work on Monday morning, now I really need to justify it. I really need to work hard in order to show that I was not stupid to give up the $10,000. So, these people are going to be surprisingly even more motivated than they were before.

Shankar Vedantam:

It's interesting. So, in some ways it's revealing what might actually be in people's hearts, including things that they might not know themselves. Once you're actually faced with an incentive, you might come to a different decision and that could actually reveal something not just to the company, but even to yourself.

Uri Gneezy:

It's really amazing how little we understand our preferences in many cases. So, very often we get people that get a job offer and then they decline it. And not because they needed a job offer in order to negotiate, but really because they thought... They come to San Diego, say in my case, they come from a cold place, now it's very nice outside, they enjoy it, it's a vacation. They're really happy about this. They say, "Okay, we want to live in San Diego."

Then they have the offer and they start thinking, "Oh, we have to take out three little kids from school. That's going to be hard. Where are we going to live?" They start thinking about the details and they discover that they don't want it. So, in many cases we don't really know our preferences until we face the decision that we need to make. And with the pay to quit, until you are offered $10,000, you might not even understand that you're not happy where you are. You will not be very motivated, you will not be a good worker, but you won't understand why.

Shankar Vedantam:

One of the things I've noticed as we've talked Uri, is that when we've seen all the ways that incentives work and how they don't work, it seems to me that it's really important to run lots and lots of experiments. Because what works in one context might not work in another. What works at one point in time might not work at another. I'm really struck by how little such thinking shapes our efforts, whether that's at the level of companies or the level of countries. So often managers and leaders tell themselves, "I know what needs to be done. My political loyalty is: tell me what's going to work." And especially when you feel like you are doing something important, something you care about, it's so easy to forget to question yourself, to doubt yourself.

Uri Gneezy:

It's really, really hard to understand the importance of what you said. Think about culture. So, I live in the US for 22 years now and I'm still surprised very often because I don't get the signal. So, I learned that when an American tells me, "Let's do lunch," basically they mean we don't want to see you again. Unless they say let's do lunch on Monday, right? In Israel, everyone is much more blunt.

So, you need to calibrate. And the same is true about incentives and it doesn't have to be between different cultures. It could be cultures, could be also taxi drivers versus teachers versus bankers in San Diego. And different people have different things that motivate them. I talk in the book, for example, about incentives to buy Prius, to buy hybrid cars. This will not work on the guy that is driving the big pickup truck. They don't care about the environment, they don't care about signaling that they care about the environment. You need to find the group that is really relevant for your incentives and find what works on them.

So, it's not that one size fits all. Different situations, different people, different cultures will require different things. And the way to do it is first to think about it, but then we try to see whether it works and then maybe you need to tweak it a bit. And then maybe after you have it for a while, you see that people found the way to game it, so solve this problem. So it's a dynamic process that needs a lot of data in order to make sure that you're right.

Shankar Vedantam:

Yeah, and especially I think in politics, I don't know if you'd agree with me, but I think in politics this is often not the case. If you think about so many of the political debates that we see around us, so many of them are basically saying, "I'm right because of this ideology," or, "You are wrong because of that ideology," as opposed to saying, "We can actually run an experiment to figure this out."

Uri Gneezy:

Let me ask you a question. Imagine that you have a big company and you invite two consultants. One of them tells you, "I know the solution to your problem. Give me a million dollars and I solve your problem immediately. No problem. Everything is good." And the other consultant tells you, "I have no clue what's the right thing, but I can design a study that will tell you."

Which one will you take? Many people will take the first one, and I think you want your politician to know what's right. You don't want them to run experiments in order to find out. You elect them because you think that they're good at it. That's what they have to present. And that's why the entire culture of politics is not, "Look, I'm good because I know how to run experiments and find out what's the right thing to do." No, I want the politician that knows what's the right thing to do. And I think that that's a mistake.

Shankar Vedantam:

Uri Gneezy is an economist at the University of California San Diego. Uri, thank you for joining me today on Hidden Brain.

Uri Gneezy:

It was a great pleasure. Thank you.

Shankar Vedantam:

Hidden Brain is produced by Hidden Brain Media. Our audio production team includes Brigid McCarthy, Annie Murphy Paul, Kristin Wong, Laura Kwerel, Ryan Katz, Autumn Barnes, and Andrew Chadwick. Tara Boyle is our executive producer. I'm Hidden Brain's executive editor. For today's unsung hero, we bring you a story from our sister show, My Unsung Hero. The story comes from Sarah Feldman.

Sarah Feldman:

In 2001, my hometown of Houston was hit by a tropical storm and I was on vacation in Connecticut. We couldn't go home that day, of course, so my father decided to take me to the Beinecke Rare Book & Manuscript Library in Yale University. I was around 13 or 14 years old, and I was asking this gentleman, named Bill Carver, a bunch of questions like, "How do you keep all these rare books okay? And what's the oldest book you have?"

And then I told him about how my grandparents went into my house that was flooded, and all of my books, lots of them, because I was a big reader as a child, were destroyed. And he said to me, "Sarah, I'm going to send you a book in the mail so you can start your collection again." And he did. And I got a really nice book called The Medieval Book by Barbara A. Shailor. And I also received a letter in the mail and I'd like to read it to you.

December 8th, 2001. Dear Sarah, I have often thought of you and your family and that terrible flood of 2000. He meant 2001. As promised, enclosed is a rather scholarly book, which may be slightly mature for your age, but I thought it might help you shape your new library collection. And as the years progress, this book may grow in stature and value to you. Have a happy holiday season. Wish you and loved ones all the best. Cordially, Bill Carver.

I want to tell him that I'm 34 now and my life is great. I'm married, I have a dog, and my partner and I like to visit cathedrals in Europe and go to the Cloisters Museum in New York City from time to time. And I'm obsessed with medieval art. I actually sent the library a letter during the pandemic, but I never heard back. I'm not sure if he's alive still because he seemed old to me when I was 14 at the time. But I'd just love to tell Bill Carver that he changed my life.

Shankar Vedantam:

Sarah Feldman lives in New York City where she has her own jewelry business. If you like today's episode, please be sure to share it with a few friends. I'm Shankar Vedantam. See you soon.


Podcast:

Subscribe to the Hidden Brain Podcast on your favorite podcast player so you never miss an episode.

Newsletter:

Go behind the scenes, see what Shankar is reading and find more useful resources and links.

Hidden Brain Media